Eliazar Marchenko's Profile Image

Eliazar Marchenko

Jul 31, 2025

Eliazar Marchenko's Profile Image

Eliazar Marchenko

Jul 31, 2025

Microeconomics Chapter 1: The Economic Problem and Opportunity Cost

This opening chapter sets the scene by introducing vou to some key ideas and identifving the scone of economic analysis.

1. Scarcity and the Basic Economic Problem

Every study of economics begins with the same observation: while human wants expand without limit, the resources available to meet those wants are fixed at any moment in time. Land is of finite area, the labour force is restricted by population and hours, the stock of machines and buildings cannot be expanded overnight, and entrepreneurial ability is limited by the number of people willing and able to bear risk. Because of this imbalance, societies must decide how best to use what they have. Economists call that overall challenge the basic economic problem, and it shapes every choice made by individuals, firms, and governments.

Three questions sit at the centre of the economic problem. First, what specific goods and services will be produced, and in what quantities? Second, how will those goods be produced, meaning which production techniques and combinations of inputs will be used? Third, for whom will the goods be produced, that is, how will the output and the income generated in production be shared among the members of society? Each economic system—whether based on markets, planning or a mixture of the two—must provide answers to all three.

2. Needs, Wants, Economic Goods, and Free Goods

Within the broad category of human desires, economists distinguish needs from wants. Needs are goods and services that are essential for sustaining life and basic health. They include staple food, clean water, weather-appropriate clothin,g and secure shelter. Wants cover everything that adds comfort, enjoyment or status once basic needs are met, from an upgraded smartphone to a weekend city break. Both needs and wants must be provided out of the same scarce stock of resources, so both are subject to the economic problem.

A good or service becomes an economic good when resources that could have been put to alternative uses are required to produce it. Those resources—land, labour, capital, and enterprise—carry opportunity costs. A loaf of bread, for instance, ties up wheat, baker’s time, electricity for the oven, and retail space that could have been devoted to other products. By contrast, a free good is so plentiful that one person’s consumption does not reduce what is left for others, and no scarce resource has to be redirected. Sunlight in an empty desert at midday fits the definition of a free good. Because economic goods are scarce, they carry market prices; free goods do not.

3. Scarcity and Poverty

Scarcity affects everyone, but poverty affects only those whose income is too low to secure an acceptable standard of living. In richer households, scarcity still forces choices—because even large budgets cannot buy unlimited time or all possible experiences—but those households rarely experience poverty. Distinguishing scarcity from poverty matters because each calls for different responses. Increasing productivity can ease scarcity’s pressure, while measures such as income support and public service provision target poverty directly.

4. Scarcity and Choice

Since resources never stretch far enough to cover every possible need and want, people must prioritise. A household might postpone a holiday in order to pay for essential home repairs. A farmer with fixed acreage must decide whether to plant potatoes or onions. A government allocating tax revenue must weigh the claims of healthcare, education, defence, and transport infrastructure. In every case, the key issue that arises from the existence of scarcity is that it forces people to make choices. Each individual must choose which goods and services to consume. In other words, everyone needs to prioritise the consumption of whatever commodities they need or would like to have, as they cannot satisfy all their wants.

5. Positive and Normative Statements

Economic discussions remain clearest when they separate statements of fact from statements of opinion. A positive statement describes how the world is, was or will be, and it can, at least in principle, be checked against evidence. “An increase in the price of petrol reduces the quantity demanded” is positive because it can be tested and verified. A normative statement expresses an opinion and so depends on a value judgement. “The government should raise the petrol tax to cut congestion” is normative because it is not possible to measure and verify; it relies on ethical or political views about pollution and fairness. Keeping the two types of statement distinct prevents disagreements over data from becoming tangled with disagreements over social objectives.

6. Economic Agents

Decisions about resource use are made by three broad groups, known as economic agents. Households choose what to buy and in what quantities, decide how many hours to work and how much education to pursue, and supply labour to firms. Firms organise production: they hire workers, rent or buy land, invest in capital equipment, and decide which goods or services to bring to market. Governments tax, spend, borrow, and regulate. They provide public services, build infrastructure, protect property rights, and aim to stabilise the overall economy.

7. Objectives and Behaviour of Economic Agents

Households generally try to maximise utility, the satisfaction gained from consuming goods and enjoying leisure. Firms usually aim to maximise profit, defined as total revenue minus total cost, though some firms may also pursue growth, brand reputation or environmental targets. Governments blend multiple objectives, such as stable prices, high employment, steady growth and an equitable income distribution.

Economic theory often starts with the assumption that agents behave rationally, comparing marginal benefits with marginal costs and choosing the option that yields the greatest net gain. Real-world decisions sometimes diverge from strict rationality because information is incomplete, preferences can change, and people are influenced by habits or social norms. Nonetheless, the rational model provides a useful benchmark for analysing choices.

8. Factors of Production

All production combines the four factors of production.

  • Land covers all natural resources, including soil, forests, mineral deposits, and rivers.

  • Labour is human effort, the work of labourers.

  • Capital refers to man-made assets for production, such as machines, factories, buildings, roads, and computer software.

  • Enterprise is the coordinating and risk-bearing factor that brings the other three together to create output.

Each factor earns a specific reward: land earns rent, labour earns wages and salaries, capital earns interest (and dividends where equity is involved), and enterprise earns profit. The reward to each factor reflects its contribution and scarcity. Rent compensates landowners for granting others the use of natural resources. Wages and salaries reward workers for the time, effort and skills they supply. Interest is paid to those who defer present consumption and provide funds that finance capital goods. Profit accrues to entrepreneurs who successfully organise production and bear the risk that revenue may not cover cost.

9. Opportunity Cost

Every choice involves giving up the best alternative use of the resources employed. The opportunity cost of attending a concert is the pleasure you would have gained from the next-best activity, perhaps meeting friends. For a government, the opportunity cost of building a new motorway may be the medical facilities that could have been funded instead. Opportunity cost is measured in the value of what is sacrificed—utility, revenue or output—not merely in monetary terms. Recognising opportunity cost makes the real trade-offs in every decision visible and encourages more informed choices.

10. The Production Possibility Curve

The Production Possibility Curve (PPC) is a diagram that shows the maximum combinations of two goods—or two broad categories of goods—that an economy can produce using all its resources efficiently at a given level of technology. Suppose the horizontal axis measures tonnes of potatoes and the vertical axis measures tonnes of onions. Any point on the curve represents an efficient allocation: all land, labour, capital, and enterprise are fully employed. Points inside the curve indicate that some resources are idle or misallocated. Points outside are unattainable given current resources and current technology.

The PPC is usually bowed outward. Resources are not equally suited to every use. Land that grows onions well may not grow potatoes well, so as more potatoes are produced, the farmer must switch from the most suitable land to less suitable plots, raising the marginal opportunity cost. This pattern is known as the law of increasing opportunity cost.

11. Capital Goods, Consumer Goods, and Long-Run Growth

Instead of two agricultural crops, the axes of the PPC can show capital goods on one axis and consumer goods on the other. Capital goods, like machines, factories, and software, do not directly satisfy wants but raise future productive capacity. Consumer goods—food, clothing, entertainment—provide immediate satisfaction. If an economy chooses more capital goods now, it sacrifices some current consumption. In the future, however, the larger capital stock shifts the PPC outward, allowing more of both types of goods. The outward movement represents long-run economic growth.

12. Shifts in the PPC

The PPC shifts when the economy’s productive capacity changes. An outward shift occurs if the quantity of factors increases—through population growth, an expansion of arable land, or a higher level of capital investment—or if productivity rises because of better education, improved health, or new technology. An inward shift results from events that destroy resources or reduce efficiency, such as natural disasters, prolonged conflict, or large-scale emigration of skilled workers. Distinguishing between a movement along a fixed PPC and a shift of the entire curve helps to clarify whether an observed change in output is due to reallocating resources or to altering the quantity or productivity of those resources.

13. Free-Market and Command Economies: Strengths and Weaknesses

How a society answers the basic economic problem depends on the system it uses to allocate resources. In a free-market economy, most decisions are made by private individuals and firms responding to prices. Rising prices signal scarcity, attract resources, and encourage innovation. Advantages of this system include strong incentives for efficiency, a wide variety of goods and services, and flexibility in responding to consumer preferences. Disadvantages include unequal distribution of income, under-provision of goods that have large external benefits, and potential instability when speculative bubbles form and burst.

In a command economy, a central authority—usually the government—sets output targets, allocates labour and capital, and may fix prices. The system can quickly redirect resources toward large projects, pursue egalitarian goals, and focus investment on heavy industry or defence. Its disadvantages arise from limited local information: planners may set inappropriate targets, leading to shortages or surpluses; product variety is often narrow; and incentives for cost-saving innovation can be weak.

Most contemporary societies operate as mixed economies, combining market forces with government intervention. The state taxes and regulates, supplies education and healthcare, funds public infrastructure, and corrects market failures, while leaving most day-to-day production and consumption decisions to private agents. The mix between market and state involvement varies across countries and evolves over time.

14. Behavioural Considerations and Rational Choice

While the core model assumes rational decision making—comparing marginal benefits with marginal costs—real behaviour often deviates from pure rationality. Consumers may follow habits, firms may pursue growth rather than profit, and governments may be influenced by political pressures. Recognising these behavioural influences does not overturn the basic framework; instead, it refines predictions and helps explain why actual outcomes sometimes differ from the results predicted by perfectly rational models.

Next Article

Next Article

Next Article

Microeconomics Chapter 2: The Allocation of Resources, Specialisation and Trade

Microeconomics Chapter 2: The Allocation of Resources, Specialisation and Trade

Microeconomics Chapter 2: The Allocation of Resources, Specialisation and Trade